enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Nash equilibrium - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Nash_equilibrium

    The concept of a mixed-strategy equilibrium was introduced by John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern in their 1944 book The Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, but their analysis was restricted to the special case of zero-sum games. They showed that a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium will exist for any zero-sum game with a finite set of ...

  3. Strategy (game theory) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Strategy_(game_theory)

    Mixed strategy Nash equilibria are equilibria where at least one player is playing a mixed strategy. While Nash proved that every finite game has a Nash equilibrium, not all have pure strategy Nash equilibria. For an example of a game that does not have a Nash equilibrium in pure strategies, see Matching pennies.

  4. Purification theorem - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Purification_theorem

    In game theory, the purification theorem was contributed by Nobel laureate John Harsanyi in 1973. [1] The theorem justifies a puzzling aspect of mixed strategy Nash equilibria: each player is wholly indifferent between each of the actions he puts non-zero weight on, yet he mixes them so as to make every other player also indifferent.

  5. Battle of the sexes (game theory) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Battle_of_the_sexes_(game...

    The mixed strategy Nash equilibrium is inefficient: the players will miscoordinate with probability 13/25, leaving each player with an expected return of 6/5 (less than the payoff of 2 from each's less favored pure strategy equilibrium). It remains unclear how expectations would form that would result in a particular equilibrium being played out.

  6. Best response - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Best_response

    In game theory, the best response is the strategy (or strategies) which produces the most favorable outcome for a player, taking other players' strategies as given. [1] The concept of a best response is central to John Nash's best-known contribution, the Nash equilibrium, the point at which each player in a game has selected the best response (or one of the best responses) to the other players ...

  7. Stag hunt - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Stag_hunt

    Formally, a stag hunt is a game with two pure strategy Nash equilibria—one that is risk dominant and another that is payoff dominant. The payoff matrix in Figure 1 illustrates a generic stag hunt, where > >. In addition to the pure strategy Nash equilibria there is one mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. This equilibrium depends on the payoffs ...

  8. Chicken (game) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Chicken_(game)

    The best response mappings agree (i.e., cross) at three points. The first two Nash equilibria are in the top left and bottom right corners, where one player chooses one strategy, the other player chooses the opposite strategy. The third Nash equilibrium is a mixed strategy which lies along the diagonal from the bottom left to top right corners.

  9. Matching pennies - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Matching_pennies

    Matching pennies is used primarily to illustrate the concept of mixed strategies and a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. [1] This game has no pure strategy Nash equilibrium since there is no pure strategy (heads or tails) that is a best response to a best response. In other words, there is no pair of pure strategies such that neither player ...