enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Allocative efficiency - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Allocative_efficiency

    In the single-price model, at the point of allocative efficiency price is equal to marginal cost. [3] [4] At this point the social surplus is maximized with no deadweight loss (the latter being the value society puts on that level of output produced minus the value of resources used to achieve that level). Allocative efficiency is the main tool ...

  3. Economic efficiency - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economic_efficiency

    When drawing diagrams for businesses, allocative efficiency is satisfied if output is produced at the point where marginal cost is equal to average revenue. This is the case for the long-run equilibrium of perfect competition. Productive efficiency occurs when units of goods are being supplied at the lowest possible average total cost.

  4. Production–possibility frontier - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Production–possibility...

    By doing so, it defines productive efficiency in the context of that production set: a point on the frontier indicates efficient use of the available inputs (such as points B, D and C in the graph), a point beneath the curve (such as A) indicates inefficiency, and a point beyond the curve (such as X) indicates impossibility.

  5. Perfect competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Perfect_competition

    Perfect competition provides both allocative efficiency and productive efficiency: Such markets are allocatively efficient, as output will always occur where marginal cost is equal to average revenue i.e. price (MC = AR).

  6. Monopoly - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly

    Average-cost pricing does also have some disadvantages. By setting price equal to the intersection of the demand curve and the average total cost curve, the firm's output is allocatively inefficient as the price is less than the marginal cost (which is the output quantity for a perfectly competitive and allocatively efficient market).

  7. Contract curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contract_curve

    By varying the weighting parameter b, one can trace out the entire contract curve: If b = 1 the problem is the same as the previous problem, and it identifies an efficient point at one edge of the lens formed by the indifference curves of the initial endowment; if b = 0 all the weight is on person 2's utility instead of person 1's, and so the ...

  8. Edgeworth box - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Edgeworth_box

    Then in order to reposition society at the desired point α' it is not necessary for the government to redistribute resources in such a way that Octavio holds (α' x,α' y) and Abby holds the complement: it is sufficient to reallocate resources to take the economy to any point (say α) on the price line through α', and then leave the market to ...

  9. Monopoly price - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_price

    The loss in both surplus' are deemed allocatively inefficient and not socially optimal. In contrast, when the firm has more information and discrimination is present, monopoly pricing becomes increasingly efficient as it approaches perfect discrimination through the various forms of price discrimination: Quantity Discount; Market Segregation