enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Nash equilibrium - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Nash_equilibrium

    For instance if a player prefers "Yes", then that set of strategies is not a Nash equilibrium. But if every player prefers not to switch (or is indifferent between switching and not) then the strategy profile is a Nash equilibrium. Thus, each strategy in a Nash equilibrium is a best response to the other players' strategies in that equilibrium ...

  3. Purification theorem - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Purification_theorem

    In game theory, the purification theorem was contributed by Nobel laureate John Harsanyi in 1973. [1] The theorem justifies a puzzling aspect of mixed strategy Nash equilibria: each player is wholly indifferent between each of the actions he puts non-zero weight on, yet he mixes them so as to make every other player also indifferent.

  4. Strategy (game theory) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Strategy_(game_theory)

    However, many games do have pure strategy Nash equilibria (e.g. the Coordination game, the Prisoner's dilemma, the Stag hunt). Further, games can have both pure strategy and mixed strategy equilibria. An easy example is the pure coordination game, where in addition to the pure strategies (A,A) and (B,B) a mixed equilibrium exists in which both ...

  5. Potential game - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Potential_game

    The potential function is a useful tool to analyze equilibrium properties of games, since the incentives of all players are mapped into one function, and the set of pure Nash equilibria can be found by locating the local optima of the potential function. Convergence and finite-time convergence of an iterated game towards a Nash equilibrium can ...

  6. Strictly determined game - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Strictly_determined_game

    In game theory, a strictly determined game is a two-player zero-sum game that has at least one Nash equilibrium with both players using pure strategies.The value of a strictly determined game is equal to the value of the equilibrium outcome.

  7. Price of stability - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_of_stability

    Anshelevich et al. studied network design games and showed that a pure strategy Nash equilibrium always exists and the price of stability of this game is at most the nth harmonic number in directed graphs. For undirected graphs Anshelevich and others presented a tight bound on the price of stability of 4/3 for a single source and two players case.

  8. Continuous game - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Continuous_game

    For any separable game there exists at least one Nash equilibrium where player i mixes at most + pure strategies. [2] Whereas an equilibrium strategy for a non-separable game may require an uncountably infinite support, a separable game is guaranteed to have at least one Nash equilibrium with finitely supported mixed strategies.

  9. Best response - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Best_response

    In game theory, the best response is the strategy (or strategies) which produces the most favorable outcome for a player, taking other players' strategies as given. [1] The concept of a best response is central to John Nash's best-known contribution, the Nash equilibrium, the point at which each player in a game has selected the best response (or one of the best responses) to the other players ...