enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Bertrand–Edgeworth model - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand–Edgeworth_model

    Joseph Louis François Bertrand (1822–1900) developed the model of Bertrand competition in oligopoly. This approach was based on the assumption that there are at least two firms producing a homogenous product with constant marginal cost (this could be constant at some positive value, or with zero marginal cost as in Cournot).

  3. Profit maximization - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Profit_maximization

    Profit maximization using the total revenue and total cost curves of a perfect competitor. To obtain the profit maximizing output quantity, we start by recognizing that profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost (). Given a table of costs and revenues at each quantity, we can either compute equations or plot the data directly on a graph.

  4. Oligopoly - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Oligopoly

    If the firms are colluding in the oligopoly, they can set the price at a high profit-maximising level. Perfect and imperfect knowledge: Oligopolies have perfect knowledge of their own cost and demand functions, but their inter-firm information may be incomplete. If firms in an oligopoly collude, information between firms then may become perfect.

  5. Perfect competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Perfect_competition

    A monopolist can set a price in excess of costs, making an economic profit. The above diagram shows a monopolist (only one firm in the market) that obtains a (monopoly) economic profit. An oligopoly usually has economic profit also, but operates in a market with more than just one firm (they must share available demand at the market price).

  6. Differentiated Bertrand competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Differentiated_Bertrand...

    p 1 = firm 1's price level pr unit; p 2 = firm 2's price level pr unit; b 1 = slope coefficient for how much firm 2's price affects firm 1's demand; b 2 = slope coefficient for how much firm 1's price affects firm 2's demand; q 1 =A 1-a 1 *p 1 +b 1 *p 2; q 2 =A 2-a 2 *p 2 +b 2 *p 1; The above figure presents the best response functions of the ...

  7. Edgeworth paradox - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Edgeworth_paradox

    The Edgeworth model shows that the oligopoly price fluctuates between the perfect competition market and the perfect monopoly, and there is no stable equilibrium. [6] Unlike the Bertrand paradox, the situation of both companies charging zero-profit prices is not an equilibrium, since either company can raise its price and generate profits.

  8. Kinked demand - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kinked_demand

    Therefore, the first derivative point is undefined and leads to a jump discontinuity in the marginal revenue curve. Classical economic theory assumes that a profit-maximizing producer with some market power (either due to oligopoly or monopolistic competition ) will set marginal costs equal to marginal revenue .

  9. Corner solution - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Corner_solution

    This diagram shows an example corner solution where the optimal bundle lies on the x-intercept at point (M,0). IC 1 is not a solution as it does not fully utilise the entire budget, IC 3 is unachievable as it exceeds the total amount of the budget. The optimal solution in this example is M units of good X and 0 units of good Y.