enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Willingness to pay - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Willingness_to_pay

    According to the constructed preference view, consumer willingness to pay is a context-sensitive construct; that is, a consumer's WTP for a product depends on the concrete decision context. For example, consumers tend to be willing to pay more for a soft drink in a luxury hotel resort in comparison to a beach bar or a local retail store.

  3. Becker–DeGroot–Marschak method - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Becker–DeGroot–Marschak...

    The Becker–DeGroot–Marschak method (BDM), named after Gordon M. Becker, Morris H. DeGroot and Jacob Marschak for the 1964 Behavioral Science paper, "Measuring Utility by a Single-Response Sequential Method" is an incentive-compatible procedure used in experimental economics to measure willingness to pay (WTP).

  4. Value of life - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Value_of_life

    On conducting the benefit-cost analysis, the team measured each dollar value of an environmental benefit by estimating a how many dollars a person is willing to pay in order to decrease or eliminate a current threat to their health, otherwise known as their "willingness-to-pay" (WTP). The WTP of the U.S. population was estimated and summed for ...

  5. Willingness to accept - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Willingness_to_accept

    In contrast, the willingness to pay is defined by u ( w 0 − W T P , 0 ) = u ( w 0 , 1 ) . {\displaystyle u(w_{0}-WTP,0)=u(w_{0},1).} That is, the willingness to pay to avoid the adverse change equates the post-change utility, diminished by the presence of the adverse change (on the right side), with utility without the adverse change but with ...

  6. Samuelson condition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Samuelson_condition

    The sum of the marginal benefits represent the aggregate willingness to pay or aggregate demand. The marginal cost is, under competitive market conditions, the supply for public goods. Hence the Samuelson condition can be thought of as a generalization of supply and demand concepts from private to public goods.

  7. Contingent valuation - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contingent_valuation

    Many economists question the use of stated preference to determine willingness to pay for a good, preferring to rely on people's revealed preferences in binding market transactions. Early contingent valuation surveys were often open-ended questions of the form "how much compensation would you demand for the destruction of X area" or "how much ...

  8. Value-based pricing - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Value-based_pricing

    The value that a consumer gives to a good or service, can then be defined as their willingness to pay for it (in monetary terms) or the amount of time and resources they would be willing to give up for it. [2] For example, a painting may be priced at a higher cost than the price of a canvas and paints. If set using the value-based approach, its ...

  9. Lindahl tax - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lindahl_tax

    For the 80th acre, her marginal willingness to pay has decreased down to zero. Figure 2: Tom's marginal willingness to pay. Figure 2 shows Tom's marginal willingness to pay for a public park. Unlike Sarah, for the first acre of park he is willing to pay $40, and for the 40th acre of park he has a marginal willingness to pay of $20.