enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Margin (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Margin_(economics)

    The marginal cost curve is the marginal cost of an additional unit at each given quantity. The law of diminishing returns states the marginal cost of an additional unit of production for an organisation or business increases as the quantity produced increases. [8] Consequently, the marginal cost curve is an increasing function for large ...

  3. Marginal revenue - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_revenue

    The marginal revenue curve is affected by the same factors as the demand curve – changes in income, changes in the prices of complements and substitutes, changes in populations, etc. [15] These factors can cause the MR curve to shift and rotate. [16] Marginal revenue curve differs under perfect competition and imperfect competition (monopoly ...

  4. Convex preferences - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Convex_preferences

    A set of convex-shaped indifference curves displays convex preferences: Given a convex indifference curve containing the set of all bundles (of two or more goods) that are all viewed as equally desired, the set of all goods bundles that are viewed as being at least as desired as those on the indifference curve is a convex set.

  5. Profit maximization - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Profit_maximization

    Marginal revenue equals zero when the total revenue curve has reached its maximum value. An example would be a scheduled airline flight. The marginal costs of flying one more passenger on the flight are negligible until all the seats are filled. The airline would maximize profit by filling all the seats.

  6. Convexity in economics - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Convexity_in_economics

    For example, a solid cube is convex; however, anything that is hollow or dented, for example, a crescent shape, is non‑convex. Trivially, the empty set is convex. More formally, a set Q is convex if, for all points v 0 and v 1 in Q and for every real number λ in the unit interval [0,1], the point (1 − λ) v 0 + λv 1. is a member of Q.

  7. Income–consumption curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Income–consumption_curve

    In figure 3, the income–consumption curve bends back on itself as with an increase income, the consumer demands more of X 2 and less of X 1. [3] The income–consumption curve in this case is negatively sloped and the income elasticity of demand will be negative. [4] Also the price effect for X 2 is positive, while it is negative for X 1. [3]

  8. Marginal rate of substitution - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_rate_of_substitution

    For example, if the MRS xy = 2, the consumer will give up 2 units of Y to obtain 1 additional unit of X. As one moves down a (standardly convex) indifference curve, the marginal rate of substitution decreases (as measured by the absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve, which decreases).

  9. Consumption function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Consumption_function

    Graphical representation of the consumption function, where a is autonomous consumption (affected by interest rates, consumer expectations, etc.), b is the marginal propensity to consume and Yd is disposable income. In economics, the consumption function describes a relationship between consumption and disposable income.