enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Theory of the firm - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Theory_of_the_firm

    The Economics of the Firm. Cambridge: Blackwell. ISBN 978-0-631-14075-7. Foss, Nicolai J., ed. (2000). The Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives on Business and Management. Taylor and Francis. v. I–IV. Chapter preview links, including Bengt Holmström and Jean Tirole, "The Theory of the Firm," v. I, pp. 148–222

  3. Bertrand competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand_competition

    It means that the marginal cost of Firm 2 is higher than the marginal cost of Firm 1. Under this situation, firm 2 can only set their price equal to their marginal cost. On the other hand, Firm 1 can choose its price between its marginal cost and Firm 2's marginal cost. Thus, there are a lot of points for Firm 1 to set its price.

  4. Monopolistic competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopolistic_competition

    A firm making profits in the short run will nonetheless only break even in the long run because demand will decrease and average total cost will increase, meaning that in the long run, a monopolistically competitive company will make zero economic profit. This illustrates the amount of influence the company has over the market; because of brand ...

  5. The Nature of the Firm - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Nature_of_the_Firm

    This is a countervailing cost to the use of the firm. [8] Coase argues that the size of a firm (as measured by how many contractual relations are "internal" to the firm and how many "external") is a result of finding an optimal balance between the competing tendencies of the costs outlined above.

  6. Perfect competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Perfect_competition

    If the cost of changing a firm's manufacturing process to produce the substitute is also relatively "immaterial" in relationship to the firm's overall profit and cost, this is sufficient to ensure that an economic situation isn't significantly different from a perfectly competitive economic market. [8]

  7. Market structure - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_structure

    N-firm concentration ratio, N-firm concentration ratio is a common measure of market structure. This gives the combined market share of the N largest firms in the market. [ 9 ] For example, if the 5-firm concentration ratio in the United States smart phone industry is about .8, which indicates that the combined market share of the five largest ...

  8. Bertrand paradox (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand_paradox_(economics)

    If prices are discrete (for example have to take integer values) then one firm has to undercut the other by at least one cent. This implies that the price one cent above MC is now an equilibrium: if the other firm sets the price one cent above MC, the other firm can undercut it and capture the whole market, but this will earn it no profit.

  9. Managerial economics - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Managerial_economics

    Production costs directly affect a firm's profitability. In order to maximise profits, firms identify the cost minimising output level for a firm where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. The most common types of costs that are factored into this decision include: [89] Fixed costs; Variable costs; Marginal cost; Average total cost; Sunk costs