enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Willingness to pay - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Willingness_to_pay

    According to the constructed preference view, consumer willingness to pay is a context-sensitive construct; that is, a consumer's WTP for a product depends on the concrete decision context. For example, consumers tend to be willing to pay more for a soft drink in a luxury hotel resort in comparison to a beach bar or a local retail store.

  3. Value of life - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Value_of_life

    The value of statistical life (VSL) in Singapore was estimated in 2007 via a contingent valuation survey that elicits willingness-to-pay (WTP) for mortality risk reductions, which interviewed 801 Singaporeans and Singapore Permanent Residents aged 40 and above, entailing a value of statistical life of approximately S$850,000 to S$2.05 million ...

  4. Hedonic damages - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hedonic_damages

    The willingness-to-pay model is based on measuring what people pay for safety that results in small reductions in their risk of death. For example, if average people are willing to pay $25 for a carbon monoxide detector that stands a one in two hundred thousand chance of saving their life, the model would imply that such purchasers value their ...

  5. Economic surplus - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economic_surplus

    Consumer surplus is the difference between the maximum price a consumer is willing to pay and the actual price they do pay. If a consumer is willing to pay more for a unit of a good than the current asking price, they are getting more benefit from the purchased product than they would if the price was their maximum willingness to pay.

  6. Willingness to accept - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Willingness_to_accept

    In contrast, the willingness to pay is defined by u ( w 0 − W T P , 0 ) = u ( w 0 , 1 ) . {\displaystyle u(w_{0}-WTP,0)=u(w_{0},1).} That is, the willingness to pay to avoid the adverse change equates the post-change utility, diminished by the presence of the adverse change (on the right side), with utility without the adverse change but with ...

  7. Becker–DeGroot–Marschak method - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Becker–DeGroot–Marschak...

    The Becker–DeGroot–Marschak method (BDM), named after Gordon M. Becker, Morris H. DeGroot and Jacob Marschak for the 1964 Behavioral Science paper, "Measuring Utility by a Single-Response Sequential Method" is an incentive-compatible procedure used in experimental economics to measure willingness to pay (WTP).

  8. Travel cost analysis - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Travel_cost_analysis

    The aim of the method is to calculate willingness to pay for a constant price facility. The technique was first suggested by the statistician Harold Hotelling in a 1947 letter to the director of the National Park Service of the United States for a method to measure the benefit of National Parks to the public. [1]

  9. Reservation price - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Reservation_price

    A reservation price can be used to help calculate the consumer surplus or the producer surplus with reference to the equilibrium price. The reason why consumers are able to experience a surplus is due to single pricing, which put simply is the same price being charged to every consumer at a given level of output. Some buyers are therefore ...