enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Bertrand competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand_competition

    Therefore, the sole equilibrium in the Bertrand model emerges when both firms establish a price equal to unit cost, known as the competitive price. [9] It is to highlight that the Bertrand equilibrium is a weak Nash-equilibrium. The firms lose nothing by deviating from the competitive price: it is an equilibrium simply because each firm can ...

  3. Bertrand paradox (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand_paradox_(economics)

    Bertrand's result is paradoxical because if the number of firms goes from one to two, the price decreases from the monopoly price to the competitive price and stays at the same level as the number of firms increases further. This is not very realistic, as in reality, markets featuring a small number of firms with market power typically charge a ...

  4. Differentiated Bertrand competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Differentiated_Bertrand...

    As a solution to the Bertrand paradox in economics, it has been suggested that each firm produces a somewhat differentiated product, and consequently faces a demand curve that is downward-sloping for all levels of the firm's price.

  5. Oligopoly - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Oligopoly

    The Bertrand equilibrium is the same as the competitive result. [ 53 ] [ clarification needed ] Each firm produces where P = MC {\displaystyle P={\text{MC}}} , resulting in zero profits. [ 49 ] A generalization of the Bertrand model is the Bertrand–Edgeworth model , which allows for capacity constraints and a more general cost function.

  6. Bertrand–Edgeworth model - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand–Edgeworth_model

    In microeconomics, the Bertrand–Edgeworth model of price-setting oligopoly looks at what happens when there is a homogeneous product (i.e. consumers want to buy from the cheapest seller) where there is a limit to the output of firms which are willing and able to sell at a particular price. This differs from the Bertrand competition model ...

  7. Equation-free modeling - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Equation-free_modeling

    Equation-free coarse time-stepper applied to the illustrative example differential equation system using = and () =. The solution of the differential equation rapidly moves to the slow manifold for any initial data. The coarse time-stepper solution would agree better with the full solution when the 100 factor is increased.

  8. Fundamental theorem of asset pricing - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Fundamental_theorem_of...

    In a discrete (i.e. finite state) market, the following hold: [2] The First Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing: A discrete market on a discrete probability space (,,) is arbitrage-free if, and only if, there exists at least one risk neutral probability measure that is equivalent to the original probability measure, P.

  9. Input–output model - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Input–output_model

    If the matrix is invertible then this is a linear system of equations with a unique solution, and so given some final demand vector the required output can be found. Furthermore, if the principal minors of the matrix I − A {\displaystyle I-A} are all positive (known as the Hawkins–Simon condition ), [ 6 ] the required output vector x ...