enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Inverse demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Inverse_demand_function

    The inverse linear demand function and the marginal revenue function derived from it have the following characteristics: Both functions are linear. [7] The marginal revenue function and inverse demand function have the same y intercept. [8] The x intercept of the marginal revenue function is one-half the x intercept of the inverse demand function.

  3. Demand - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Demand

    To compute the inverse demand equation, simply solve for P from the demand equation. [12] For example, if the demand equation is Q = 240 - 2P then the inverse demand equation would be P = 120 - .5Q, the right side of which is the inverse demand function. [13] The inverse demand function is useful in deriving the total and marginal revenue ...

  4. Demand curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Demand_curve

    When a non-price determinant of demand changes, the curve shifts. These "other variables" are part of the demand function. They are "merely lumped into intercept term of a simple linear demand function." [14] Thus a change in a non-price determinant of demand is reflected in a change in the x-intercept causing the curve to shift along the x ...

  5. Cobweb model - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cobweb_model

    When supply and demand are linear functions the outcomes of the cobweb model are stated above in terms of slopes, but they are more commonly described in terms of elasticities. The convergent case requires that the slope of the (inverse) supply curve be greater than the absolute value of the slope of the (inverse) demand curve:

  6. Roy's identity - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Roy's_identity

    Roy's identity reformulates Shephard's lemma in order to get a Marshallian demand function for an individual and a good from some indirect utility function.. The first step is to consider the trivial identity obtained by substituting the expenditure function for wealth or income in the indirect utility function (,), at a utility of :

  7. Markup rule - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Markup_rule

    On the other hand, a competitive firm by definition faces a perfectly elastic demand; hence it has = which means that it sets the quantity such that marginal cost equals the price. The rule also implies that, absent menu costs , a firm with market power will never choose a point on the inelastic portion of its demand curve (where ϵ ≥ − 1 ...

  8. Monopoly price - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_price

    () = inverse demand function; the price at which can be sold given the existing demand = total cost of producing . = economic profit; This is done by equating the derivative of with respect to to 0. The profit of a firm is given by total revenue (price times quantity sold) minus total cost:

  9. Slutsky equation - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Slutsky_equation

    where (,) is the Hicksian demand and (,) is the Marshallian demand, at the vector of price levels , wealth level (or, alternatively, income level) , and fixed utility level given by maximizing utility at the original price and income, formally given by the indirect utility function (,).