enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Transaction cost - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Transaction_cost

    Transaction cost as a formal theory started in the late 1960s and early 1970s. [13] And refers to the "Costs of Market Transactions" in his seminal work, The Problem of Social Cost (1960). Arguably, transaction cost reasoning became most widely known through Oliver E. Williamson's Transaction Cost Economics. Today, transaction cost economics is ...

  3. Transaction cost analysis - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Transaction_cost_analysis

    For example, application of a transaction cost model helps split Implementation Shortfall into the parts resulting from the size of the order, volatility, or paying to cover the spread. Proper attribution must also distinguish the influence of market factors (i.e. Sector , Region , Market capitalization , and Momentum ) from that of human skill.

  4. Theory of the firm - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Theory_of_the_firm

    This grows worse with firm size and more layers in the hierarchy. Empirical analyses of transaction costs have attempted to measure and operationalize transaction costs. [5] [27] Research that attempts to measure transaction costs is the most critical limit to efforts to potential falsification and validation of transaction cost economics.

  5. Social cost - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Social_cost

    Mathematically, social marginal cost is the sum of private marginal cost and the external costs. [3] For example, when selling a glass of lemonade at a lemonade stand, the private costs involved in this transaction are the costs of the lemons and the sugar and the water that are ingredients to the lemonade, the opportunity cost of the labor to combine them into lemonade, as well as any ...

  6. The Market for Lemons - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Market_for_Lemons

    Akerlof's theory of the "Market for Lemons" paper applies to markets with information asymmetry, focusing on the used car market. Information asymmetry within the market relates to the seller having more information about the quality of the car as opposed to the buyer, creating adverse selection. [1]

  7. Hold-up problem - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hold-up_problem

    In economics, the hold-up problem is central to the theory of incomplete contracts, and shows the difficulty in writing complete contracts. A hold-up problem arises when two factors are present: Parties to a future transaction must make noncontractible relationship-specific investments before the transaction takes place.

  8. The Problem of Social Cost - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Problem_of_Social_Cost

    Coase used the example of pollution (raised by George Stigler in The Theory of Price, 1952) several times: he argued that arbitrage between actors in a market with low transaction costs could lead to an efficient market solution. [6] Coase extends this framework throughout his development of a functional theorem concerning externalities.

  9. Contract theory - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contract_theory

    Contract theory in economics began with 1991 Nobel Laureate Ronald H. Coase's 1937 article "The Nature of the Firm". Coase notes that "the longer the duration of a contract regarding the supply of goods or services due to the difficulty of forecasting, then the less likely and less appropriate it is for the buyer to specify what the other party should do."