Search results
Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
Milton Friedman (/ ˈ f r iː d m ən / ⓘ; July 31, 1912 – November 16, 2006) was an American economist and statistician who received the 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his research on consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and the complexity of stabilization policy. [4]
The American economist Milton Friedman developed the permanent income hypothesis in his 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function. [7] In his book, Friedman posits a theory that explained how and why future expectations change consumption. [8] Friedman's 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function created the basis for consumption ...
In economics, the consumption function describes a relationship between consumption and disposable income. [ 1 ] [ 2 ] The concept is believed to have been introduced into macroeconomics by John Maynard Keynes in 1936, who used it to develop the notion of a government spending multiplier .
The Keynesian consumption function is also known as the absolute income hypothesis, as it only bases consumption on current income and ignores potential future income (or lack of). Criticism of this assumption led to the development of Milton Friedman's permanent income hypothesis and Franco Modigliani's life cycle hypothesis.
The Friedman–Savage utility function is the utility function postulated in the theory that Milton Friedman and Leonard J. Savage put forth in their 1948 paper. [1] They argued that the curvature of an individual's utility function differs based upon the amount of wealth the individual has.
Average propensity to consume (APC) (as well as the marginal propensity to consume) is a concept developed by John Maynard Keynes to analyze the consumption function, which is a formula where total consumption expenditures (C) of a household consist of autonomous consumption (C a) and income (Y) (or disposable income (Y d)) multiplied by marginal propensity to consume (c 1 or MPC).
A new Friedman biography ably explores the economist's ideas but sidesteps the libertarian movement he was central to. The Best of Reason: Milton Friedman Was No Conservative Skip to main content
Friedman's updated quantity theory also allowed for the possibility of using monetary or fiscal policy to remedy a major downturn. [91] Friedman broke with Keynes by arguing that money demand is relatively stable—even during a downturn. [90] Monetarists argued that "fine-tuning" through fiscal and monetary policy is counterproductive.