enow.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results from the WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Nash equilibrium - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Nash_equilibrium

    For instance if a player prefers "Yes", then that set of strategies is not a Nash equilibrium. But if every player prefers not to switch (or is indifferent between switching and not) then the strategy profile is a Nash equilibrium. Thus, each strategy in a Nash equilibrium is a best response to the other players' strategies in that equilibrium ...

  3. Battle of the sexes (game theory) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Battle_of_the_sexes_(game...

    The mixed strategy Nash equilibrium is inefficient: the players will miscoordinate with probability 13/25, leaving each player with an expected return of 6/5 (less than the payoff of 2 from each's less favored pure strategy equilibrium). It remains unclear how expectations would form that would result in a particular equilibrium being played out.

  4. Solution concept - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Solution_concept

    A Nash equilibrium is a strategy profile (a strategy profile specifies a strategy for every player, e.g. in the above prisoners' dilemma game (cooperate, defect) specifies that prisoner 1 plays cooperate and prisoner 2 plays defect) in which every strategy played by every agent (agent i) is a best response to every other strategy played by all the other opponents (agents j for every j≠i) .

  5. Potential game - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Potential_game

    The change in potential is ΔP = P(+1, a 2) – P(–1, a 2) = (b 1 + b 2 a 2 + w a 2) – (–b 1 + b 2 a 2 – w a 2) = 2 b 1 + 2 w a 2 = Δu 1. The solution for player 2 is equivalent. Using numerical values b 1 = 2, b 2 = −1, w = 3, this example transforms into a simple battle of the sexes, as shown in Figure 2. The game has two pure Nash ...

  6. Price of stability - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_of_stability

    Anshelevich et al. studied network design games and showed that a pure strategy Nash equilibrium always exists and the price of stability of this game is at most the nth harmonic number in directed graphs. For undirected graphs Anshelevich and others presented a tight bound on the price of stability of 4/3 for a single source and two players case.

  7. Correlated equilibrium - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Correlated_equilibrium

    The two pure strategy Nash equilibria are (D, C) and (C, D). There is also a mixed strategy equilibrium where both players chicken out with probability 2/3. Now consider a third party (or some natural event) that draws one of three cards labeled: ( C , C ), ( D , C ), and ( C , D ), with the same probability, i.e. probability 1/3 for each card.

  8. Best response - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Best_response

    In game theory, the best response is the strategy (or strategies) which produces the most favorable outcome for a player, taking other players' strategies as given. [1] The concept of a best response is central to John Nash's best-known contribution, the Nash equilibrium, the point at which each player in a game has selected the best response (or one of the best responses) to the other players ...

  9. Price of anarchy - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_of_anarchy

    Different concepts of equilibrium can be used to model the selfish behavior of the agents, among which the most common is the Nash equilibrium. Different flavors of Nash equilibrium lead to variations of the notion of Price of Anarchy as Pure Price of Anarchy (for deterministic equilibria), Mixed Price of Anarchy (for randomized equilibria ...